The Commercial AND Financial Chronicle April 6, 1967
MONETARY POLICY BLUNDER CAUSED HOUSING CRISIS
By Leland J. Pritchard,
Professor of Finance, the University of Kansas, Lawrence, Kansas.
The
need for hikes in Reg. “Q” is challenged by a leading professor and writer in
the field of money and banking. Prof.
Pritchard faults the Federal Reserve for needlessly collapsing the home mortgage
market in 1966 when, understandably adopting a tight money policy, it
successively raised Reg. “Q” and caused an inequitable distribution of
available credit. He calls for further
reductions in member bank deposit interest rate ceilings than those belatedly
lowered in July and September, 1966.
Says this would further reduce the ratio of time deposits, reduce bank
costs and increase profits, stimulate funds to S&L Associations., and Mutual
Savings Associations, and obviate Governmental infusions to relieve the
mortgage money shortage.
The sharp drop which occurred
in residential construction in 1966 was almost entirely a credit
phenomenon. It was the result of both a severely
curtailed flow of credit into the housing industry and the sharply rising cost
of credit. Both the reduced volume of
funds, and the higher cost of mortgage credit, were the direct consequence of
the Federal Reserves’ tight money policy.
By the third quarter of 1966
the impact of this policy had reduced housing starts, on a seasonally adjusted
annual basis, approximately 50 percent from the level prevailing at the end of
1965.
The crisis thus created in
the housing industry called for and brought forth massive infusions of
government credit, and other emergency measures. The Federal Home Loan Banks (FHLB’s) relaxed
the conditions for making advances to member savings and loan associations, and
in mid-1966 Congress appropriated $1 billion to the Federal National Mortgage Association
(FNMA) for purchases of certain private housing loans. On July 1 the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System took the unprecedented action of authorizing the Federal
Reserve banks to make their credit facilities available, through the member
banks, to the mutual savings banks and the savings and loan associations. Fortunately it was never necessary to use
this emergency measure.
It seems to be the general consensus
that the housing industry must inevitably bear the major impact of a tight
money policy. In the words of William
McChesney Martin Jr., Chairman of the Board of Governors, “Home building was
elbowed to the end of the line; residential construction activity was reduced
for below the levels needed to meet our long-term housing needs.”
In fairness to Mr. Martin and
the other member so the Board it should be said that it was neither their wish
nor intention to “elbow the housing industry to the end of the line.” This unfortunate situation was simply the
inevitable consequence of a severely restrictive monetary policy. It is with this fatalistic assumption that I
wish to take issue.
NO NEED FOR INEQUITABLE BURDEN
No responsible person
contends that the Reserve authorities were not correct in pursuing a
restrictive monetary policy in 1966.
Considering the lack of fiscal restraint exercised by the Federal
Government, particularly after the first major escalation of the Vietnam War in
June 1965, there was no alternative. But
it was not necessary that the burden of monetary restraints be imposed so
inequitably.
Federal Reserve credit policy
in 1966 can be roughly divided into three periods. The period from January through March can be
characterized as one of increasing though moderate restraint; from April
through October as a period of severe restraint, and the remainder of the year,
a period of rapid relaxation. It is with
the April through October period that we are most concerned. During this period the Federal Reserve forced
an actual reduction in member bank legal reserves, down about $1 billion from a
level of approximately $24 billion.
Since this reduction was accomplished through the open market operations
of the System, we can logically assume that a proportionate decrease in the
legal reserves of the non-member banks was also affected.
Combined
with an intense demand for loans, the contraction of reserves forced the banks
to operate with a large volume of net-borrowed reserves. The extreme point of stringency was reached
during the first week in October when net-borrowed reserves position, to a
net-free-position of approximately $500 million. The extent of the sharp reversal in monetary
policy since October 1966 is revealed in the shift from this extreme net-borrowed
reserve position to a net-free reserve position of nearly $200 million at the
present time (March 1967). As a
byproduct of the Reserves’ credit policies, the stock of money declined at an
annual rate of 1.7 per cent during the April-October period.
The
whole of 1967, however, the story is quite different. The Reserve authorities
allowed bank credit to expand during 1966 by $19.7 billion, or at an annual
rate of approximately 6 per cent. This
compares to an annually compounded rate of increase of approximately 7 per cent
in the preceding ten years, and a rate of about 5 percent for the entire period
since World War II.
Since
banks made a negligible change in their aggregate security holdings, decreasing
only $200 million from the end of 1965 to the end of 1966, the entire increase
in bank credit was available to finance loans.
During
1966 the commercial banks made a net addition of $5.5 billion to their
aggregate holdings of nonfarm mortgages.
This compares to a figure of $5.5 billion for 1965; $4.2 billion for
1964; $4.6 billion for 1963; and $3.8 billion for 1962.
BANK MORGAGES ROSE
In
other words the commercial banks cannot be faulted for the dearth of new
mortgage money in 1966. At the same time
the banks were increasing mortgage lending above previous year levels, they
were increasing their loans to business by approximately $14.2 billion. As many a businessman can now attest who has
an excessive volume of inventories on hand, it would have been far better had
the effects of the tight money policy been distributed more equitably –
specifically by denying to him the funds he thought he needed in 1966.
The
Savings & Loan industry on the other hand was able to expand its aggregate
mortgage holdings by a net amount of only$3.8 billion in 1966. This figure compares with a net increase in
1965 of $8.9 billion in 1966. This
figure compares with a net increase in 1965 of $8.9 billion; of $10.4 billion
of 1964; and of $12.1 billion in 1963.
Those
who have argued so vigorously that the lack of mortgage money was due to
disintermediation (a shift by the public from indirect investment through
financial intermediaries to direct investment), and who also insist that the
commercial banks are only another type of financial intermediary, should ponder
the above data.
WHAT SHOULD HAVE BEEN DONE
We
may now consider the question; “How could the Federal Reserve have pursued a
tighter money policy toward business and at the same time an easier money
policy toward the housing industry?” And
what is even more important to those who believe in the free enterprise system,
how could such a segmented control of the credit market be accomplished through
indirect, rather than direct controls?
The
answer is: By reducing the volume of
time deposits held by the commercial banks, and by reducing the over-all volume
of bank credit.
The
Board has the power to change the time deposit/demand deposit mix. Under its Regulation “Q” the Board has the power
to fix the maximum interest rates member banks can pay on time deposits at any
level the Board deems appropriate. By lowering the ceilings the Board can induce
a shift from time deposits, to demand deposits and, since the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation (FDIC) follows the lead of the Board of Governors, the
effect of the Board’s action to virtually all commercial banks.
It
is a fact that people choose to hold savings in the form of pass
book savings account, or multiple-maturity non-negotiable certificates of
deposit in commercial banks for about the same reasons they choose to
hold share
accounts or share certificates in Savings & Loan Associations or Savings
Deposits in Mutual Savings Banks.
If
time deposits are made less attractive fewer funds will be held in this form
and more savings will flow through the Savings and Loan association and the
Mutual Savings Banks, the principal institutional suppliers of nonfarm mortgage
credit.
SHIFT, NOT A DECREASE, IN DEMAND
DEPOSITS
A
shift from time to demand deposits and the transfer of the ownership of these
demand deposits to the Savings and Loan Associations and the Mutual Savings
Banks does not force a reduction in the size of the banking system. These transactions simply involve a shift in
the form of bank liabilities (from time to demand deposits) and a shift in the
ownership of demand deposits (from savers to Savings and Loan Associations, et
al).
The
utilization of these demand deposits by the Savings and Loan Associations and
the Mutual Savings banks also would not reduce the volume of demand deposits
held by the commercial banks, or the volume of their earning assets. In the context of their lending operations it
is only possible to reduce bank assets and demand deposits by retiring
bank-held loans.
And
in any event, a loan paid off can be replace irrespective of what is happening
to time deposits, for the size of the banking system is not determined by the
willingness of the public to save, and to entrust their savings to the
commercial banks. The aggregate size of
the banking system, and the volume of earning assets held by the banking
system-given the opportunities to make “bankable” loans – is determined by the
willingness of the Federal Reserve to supply legal reserves to the banking
system.
A
shift from time to demand deposits would not only increase the flow of funds
through the Savings and Loan Associations and the Mutual Savings Banks, and thereby
increase the funds available for mortgage financing; it would sharply reduce
bank expenses, and increase bank profits.
COSTLY TIME DEPOSITS
Using
differential cost figures prepared by the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston and
income and other data on member banks from the Federal Reserve Bulletin, I have
been able to prepare estimates on the relative cost of time and demand deposits
and estimates on the relative cost of time and demand deposits and rates of
earnings on loans for the year 1965, the last year for which adequate data are
available. The average annual cost of
maintaining a $1,000 time deposit came to $43, compared to an average cost of
$14.30 per $1,000 of demand deposits.
Thus for every shift of $1,000 from time to demand deposits bank costs
are reduce d by $27.70.
The
differential is probably greater for 1966 as it appears that interest rates
paid on time deposits have increased faster than the various other costs,
involved in administering, either time of demand deposits.
Obviously,
however, the overheated situation of the economy in 1966 required that if more
funds were to be permitted to flow into the housing industry a compensating
curtailment was required elsewhere. This
could have been accomplished by reducing the rate of growth of bank credit to
less than 6 percent.
The
shift from time to demand deposits, b y reducing excess reserves, would have
forced some credit contraction. Open
market sales by the Federal Reserve would have provided any additional pressure
for contraction if this were necessary.
EFFECT ON BANK PROFITS
Bank
credit contraction means, of course, reduced loan volume and reduce bank earnings,
but if this is accomplished by an even greater reduction in banks expenses,
bank profits will obviously increase.
And it is profits, not size, that is presumably the primary objective of
bank managements.
Using
the same source material referred to above, I estimated that member bank net
earnings per $1,000 of loans outstanding was approximately $41.10 in 1965. This figure represents gross earnings, less
those specific costs chargeable to the acquisition and administration of loans,
plus an allocation of overhead costs.
If
the net earnings per annum on $1,000 of loans is $41.10 and the net cost of
acquiring, holding and service $1,000 of time deposits is $43 this would
suggest that the banks should get out of the time deposit business altogether. This may be true, but, the reader should be
cautioned that the direct comparison of return on assets, with cost of savings,
is only valid for intermediary types of financial institutions; it is not valid
to apply such a comparison to the commercial banks.
To
determine whether time deposit banking is profitable from the standpoint of the
banking system it is necessary to answer the following question: Does a given growth in time deposits induce
the monetary authorities to follow a policy of greater ease, or less restraint,
such as will enable the banking system to acquire an additional volume of
reserves on the basis of which the banks can expand their earning assets, and
thereby their net earnings, by an amount sufficient to more than offset the
over-all increase in costs associated with the growth of time deposits?
Since
in a net sense time deposits originate exclusively from shifts out of demand
deposits (either directly or indirectly via the currency or undivided profits
account routes), and sine time deposits are more expensive to maintain than are
demand deposits; it is actually possible to increase the over-all profits of
the banking system by inducing a return shift from time to demand deposits even
though the net rate of return on loans is greater, dollar-for-dollar, than the
cost of maintaining time deposits.
Assume
for example, that the net annual return per $1,000 of loans was at the absurdly
high level of $70, far above the rate of return than now prevails. The Federal Reserve would have to force a
reduction of bank credit by more than $500 for every $1,000 shifted from time
to demand deposits, before any reduction would take place, in over-all bank
profits. The calculations are as
follows: A shift of $1,000 from time to demand deposits, decreases expenses by
$27.70. A further reduction of demand
deposits by $500 (an inevitable consequence of reducing loans by $500) reduces
expenses by $7.65, or a total reduction in expenses of $35.35. This is approximately the same as the loss in
income ($35) resulting from the reduction in loans by $500. Any further reductions in loans, unless
compensated for by additional shifts from time to demand deposits would, of
course, reduce profits.
BELATED REMEDY
On
July 20, 1966 the Reserve Authorities made the first reduction of interest rate
ceilings on time deposits since February 1, 1935. The maximum rates payable on multiple
maturity non-negotiable certificates of deposit were reduce from 5 ½ to 5
percent on certificates maturing in 90 days or more, and from 5 ½ to 5 percent
on certificates maturing in less than 90 days.
These are the consumer-type credit instruments issued by commercial
banks which are most competitive with the share accounts and share certificates of
savings and loan associations and the savings deposits of mutual
savings banks.
A
second reduction was effected on September 26, 1966 when the maximum rates on
single maturity negotiable and non-negotiable certificates of deposit of less
than $100,000 denomination were reduced from 5 ½ to 5 percent. The FDIC of course extended all of these reductions
to non-member insured banks.
Since
banks are generally paying the maximums allowed these changes had a
considerable effect on the relative attractiveness of time deposit, vis a’ vis
accounts in Savings and Loan Associations, and savings deposits in Mutual Savings
Banks. For example time deposits, which
increased $8.3 billion during the first half of 1966 and stood at a figure of
$156.8 billion in July grew by only $1.1 billion the remainder of the year,
Share accounts in Savings and Loan Associations on the other hand had $2.9
billion of their total 1966 growth of $3.5 billion, in the last half of the
year.
Furthermore,
while the aggregate of time and demand deposits continued to increase after
July, the proportion of time to demand deposits diminished. Whereas
time deposits were 105 percent of demand deposits in July, by the end of the
year, the proportion had fallen to 98 percent. These were all desirable developments.
Not
only was the flow of savings through the Savings and Loan Associations and the
Mutual Savings Banks stimulated, and more funds made available for housing
construction, but these developments had a favorable effect on bank profits.
Favorable
as these developments were, they were nevertheless inadequate to counteract
adequately the degree of stagnation and paralysis that had overtaken the
housing industry.
The
latest available seasonally adjusted annual figure for housing starts (February
1967) indicates that the industry is operating a level of about 1 million
units, a very depressed level, both historically, and in terms of our current,
and future housing needs.
What
was called for was a much greater reduction in the interest ceilings on the
consumer-type certificates of deposit. Since
the Board uses the criterion, “equalization of competition for savings” in the
fixing of rate ceilings, it is understandable why they would be loathe to lower
the rate ceilings for commercial banks significantly below the rates paid by
the FDIC for insured mutual savings banks and by the FHLB Board for member
savings and loan associations.
BANKS DO NOT COMPETE FOR SAVINGS
While
the action of the Board is understandable, it is nevertheless
indefensible. It bears repeating that
the commercial banks, from a system standpoint, do not acquire savings from
outside the system. All savings held in
the commercial banks originate within the system itself. Commercial banks are not therefore in any
meaningful sense competing with Savings and Loan Associations and Mutual
Savings Banks for the savings of the public.
Commercial
banks are credit creating institutions. The
aggregate lending capacity of the commercial banks is predicated upon the
willingness of the Federal Reserve authorities to supply the banking system
with legal reserves; it is not dependent upon the savings practices of the
public, and the willingness of the public to hold time deposits in the banks.
Commercial banks do not loan out time deposits, or the “proceeds” of time
deposits; neither do they loan out existing demand deposits, or any type of
existing asset, or liability. Commercial banks create new demand deposits when
making loans to, or buying securities from, the nonbank public.
If
the Board of Governors whishes to increase the lending capacity of the
commercial banks they always have it within power to do so. All that is required are open market
purchases by the Reserve Banks of an amount sufficient to cause a net additional
in bank legal reserves. Since open
market purchases are participated in by the customers of nonmember as well as
member banks, these operations add to nonmember, as well as to member bank
reserves.
Raising
interest ceilings on time deposits, as the Board did on five successive
occasions beginning January 1, 1957 and culminating in the disastrous increase
to 5 ½ per cent on December 6, 1965, simply allowed the banks to increase their
expenses with no concomitant increase in income. The earning assets held by the commercial
banks, from a system standpoint, are not the result of the growth of time
deposits. The sequence is not from time
deposits to earning assets, rather the sequence is from earning assets, and new
demand deposits, these two come into being simultaneously, and from “old”
demand deposits (which the public has saved) to time deposits.
CALLS FOR LOWER REG. “Q” CEILINGS
Proper
public policy calls further reductions in the interest ceilings allowable under
regulation “Q”. This would reduce
further the proportion of time to demand deposits, reduce bank costs, increase
bank profits; and stimulate an increased flow of funds through the Savings and
Loan Associations and the Mutual Savings Banks.
There would then be no need of massive infusions of government credit to
relive the shortage of mortgage money.
This
course of action would not reduce the size of the banking system, the volume of
earnings assets held by the banking system, the income received by the system,
or the opportunities of the banks to make safe and profitable loans. Quite the contrary in fact. By promoting the welfare and health of such
an important segment of the economy as is represented by the housing industry,
the health and vitality of the whole national economy will improve. The aggregate demand for loan funds will
expand, the volume of “bankable” loans will grow, and so will the banking
system, - the Federal Reserve being willing.
No comments:
Post a Comment